• Home
  • About
    • For What it’s Worth
    • Michael Rushton
    • Contact
  • AJBlogs
  • ArtsJournal

For What It's Worth

Michael Rushton on pricing the arts

Why Is Dynamic Pricing So Rarely Used?

February 28, 2013 by Michael Rushton 9 Comments

one priceAs technology has come available that allows performing arts organizations to adjust prices in light of demand, the question has arisen: is it appropriate for nonprofit theaters to employ dynamic pricing? See here and here for example.

Let’s consider the issue from a different angle: why is dynamic pricing so rarely used in the for-profit sector?

For example, at my local multiplex cinema, I will pay $5 for a weekday matinee, $7.50 for  weekday evening or weekend matinee, and $10 for a weekend evening. It doesn’t matter whether the film I see is in high demand or low, it doesn’t matter whether it is an Oscar-winner like Argo or Life of Pi, or a film whose reviews are brutal, and it doesn’t matter if I am attending during a month when cinema demand is predictably and routinely high, or low. It’s true that the cinema owner will receive different amounts for different films, as the share of receipts the cinema keeps relative to the share that goes to the distributor rises as the run of the movie extends. But as a viewer I do not see prices change. Or, to take another example, consider iTunes. For the thousands of songs they have on offer, prices are remarkably uniform. For the most part songs are either $0.99 or $1.29, regardless of the popularity of the particular tune (indeed, iTunes will even tell you the relative popularity of each song). Cinemas and music downloads come to us from commercial firms, and so have none of the qualms a nonprofit might have about whether variable prices in light of popularity are consistent with mission. They need only consider whether dynamic prices are consistent with profit. But we see remarkable uniformity in prices across offerings and over time. What could explain this?

One possibility is that the vendor does not wish to signal to buyers that one particular movie or song is not generating demand, since that would kill demand for low-performing works even faster. Such a rationale seems persuasive to me when it comes to books. Publishers charge the same prices across their catalog for, say, works of literary fiction. Since a novel requires a lot of time on the reader’s part, and it is hard to judge a book by its cover, any discount on the price of a book that suggested it was thought by the publisher to be lower quality would put an end to any readership for that book. No one wants to spend hours with a bad novel instead of a good one to save a couple of dollars. But I don’t see how that can explain uniform prices for movies or songs. We know the songs we download, and whether we like them. We know what to expect when we attend a movie, we have seen trailers, read reviews that give a good sense of whether we will enjoy the film. Changing prices for songs and films won’t affect whether I expect they will be any good.

Another possibility is what economists call “menu costs”: it is a lot of work for a manager to keep track of demand, adjust prices, and then post those prices. If I were running a restaurant that would certainly be a relevant consideration: I wouldn’t want to constantly have to revise and reprint my menu, and to do the work on a weekly basis to try to get the prices for every meal and drink “just right.” But this shouldn’t be such an issue for cinemas, who don’t have lengthy “menus”, and who don’t print their prices.

What seems most persuasive to me is an explanation from behavioral economics. As consumers, we place a value on predictability, and we are guided to some degree by “loss aversion” – we are made somewhat happy when we find an item will cost us less than we expected, but we are very disappointed when we find it will cost us more, and that disappointment is of greater magnitude than the gain from finding a sale. This gives firms an incentive to keep prices stable and predictable even when demand conditions might suggest a change in prices could be profitable. If my local cinema surprises me by charging me $15 on a Saturday night to see Silver Linings Playbook when I expected to pay $10, it is in great danger of losing all my further business, because I really don’t like that kind of surprise. And giving me a discount to see a less popular movie, charging $8 instead of $10 for me to see Rust and Bone, is a nice surprise, but not one that gives me a lot of incentive to attend the movies more. Taking all that together, the cinema is best just charging $10 on Saturday nights regardless of the film, with no surprises.

Airlines can easily use dynamic pricing: they are selling a known commodity, can easily adjust menu prices, and have a customer base without a firm expectation of what any particular flight is going to cost – when we go to book a flight we know that we don’t know what we will pay. But for cinemas it is not so easy, and we tend to see uniform prices, even when the economics would lead us to expect variable prices.

We will return to the issue of whether dynamic pricing is consistent with nonprofit mission in later posts, but for now we should realize that even commercial firms in the arts and entertainment sector find some limitations to its use.

Footnote: For more speculation on uniform movie prices see Tyler Cowen, or this scholarly work from Barak Orbach and Liran Einav.

 

Share:

  • Click to email a link to a friend (Opens in new window) Email
  • Click to share on Facebook (Opens in new window) Facebook
  • Click to share on X (Opens in new window) X
  • Click to share on LinkedIn (Opens in new window) LinkedIn
  • Click to print (Opens in new window) Print

Related

Filed Under: Uncategorized Tagged With: dynamic pricing, menu costs, movies, nonprofit, restaurants, songs

Comments

  1. Mike Hendrix says

    August 16, 2013 at 7:52 pm

    M Rushton, do you think dynamic pricing would work for golf courses?

    Reply
    • Michael Rushton says

      August 17, 2013 at 12:58 pm

      I do. Note that dynamic pricing, to my mind, is not the same as setting different green fees for different days of the week or seasons: that is commonplace. I define dynamic pricing as price adjustments in response to unanticipated levels of demand (whether high or low). So, for a golf course, a heat wave that sharply cut demand might be an occasion to temporarily reduce prices. Not knowing the golf course business though, I would expect that demand is for the most part reasonably predictable?

      Reply

Trackbacks

  1. Around the horn: Pesach edition | Createquity. says:
    March 29, 2013 at 8:08 am

    […] Rushton is the newest ArtsJournal blogger and has 15 posts up in five weeks, including ones on dynamic pricing, free admission at the Indianapolis Museum of Art, faux-expensive admission at the Metropolitan […]

    Reply
  2. For What It's Worth | How dynamic pricing works says:
    April 14, 2013 at 11:59 am

    […] recall an earlier post of mine of why dynamic pricing is rarely used – it entails the problem of potentially […]

    Reply
  3. For What It's Worth | Scalpers says:
    May 19, 2013 at 1:43 pm

    […] of dynamic pricing by concert producers might limit the role of ticket resale to some degree, but, for various reasons, dynamic pricing has not caught on so much in the arts. […]

    Reply
  4. For What It's Worth | When dynamic pricing makes sense says:
    March 11, 2014 at 11:53 am

    […] some incentives to shop when the area is less crowded. And it doesn’t come with some of the problems that arts organizations have when implementing dynamic pricing: cuts in prices don’t send an […]

    Reply
  5. For What It's Worth | Dynamic pricing at the zoo says:
    June 20, 2014 at 6:46 am

    […] have written before about why I don’t think we see much dynamic pricing in the arts; presenters […]

    Reply
  6. Blog 5 Instructions (Extra Credit/Make Up) – Marketing the Arts says:
    March 12, 2019 at 1:03 pm

    […] Dynamic Pricing in the Arts (good idea or bad in the arts?) […]

    [WORDPRESS HASHCASH] The comment’s server IP (192.0.99.135) doesn’t match the comment’s URL host IP (192.0.78.12) and so is spam.

    Reply
  7. An Executive’s Guide to Pricing Strategy Models - SlideModel says:
    July 2, 2020 at 3:10 am

    […] The earlier mentioned How to Price Effectively book, the case of Indianapolis Zoo switching to dynamic pricing is analyzed. Indianapolis Zoo switched to dynamic pricing back in 2014, transforming its business model. In the past, tickets used to cost ~$17. After they adopted dynamic pricing, the ticket could cost anywhere from $8 to $30. Several factors are analyzed to determine ticket prices dynamically. Their price optimization strategy is combined with differentiation in prices between low-demand weekdays and high-demand weekends. This is one of the success stories on organization switching to dynamic pricing, but will be dynamic pricing used in the future? Other authors have written about dynamic prices in Arts, like Michael Rushton in his article “Why Is Dynamic Pricing So Rarely Used?“. […]

    Reply

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Michael Rushton

Michael Rushton taught in the Arts Administration programs at Indiana University, and lives in Bloomington. An economist by training, he has published widely on such topics as public funding of the … MORE

About For What It’s Worth

What’s the price? Everything has one; admission, subscriptions, memberships, special exhibitions, box seats, refreshments, souvenirs, and on and on – a full menu. What the price is matters. Generally, nonprofit arts organizations in the US receive about half of their revenue as “earned income,” and … [Read More...]

Archives

Recent Comments

  • Carlo on What to do with the NEA? Make it Conservative?: “The Kennedy Center is offering $25 tickets in only select orchestra seating for the performances of Washington National Opera: Porgy…” May 20, 14:17
  • Carlo on Art in Turbulent Times: “The Kennedy Center today is selling discounted tickets for the Washington Opera for $20.” May 1, 21:31
  • Montague Gammon III on Art in Turbulent Times: “We would like to think that a Trumped Kennedy Center would experience a significant downturn in attendance, but we should…” Apr 22, 05:51
  • Ed Comet on What do to with the NEA? Pull the plug?: “The author has gone to the Grand Canyon with a magnifying glass, and found the rocks uninteresting.. The NEA does…” Apr 12, 16:42
  • Brtian Newhouse on What do to with the NEA? Pull the plug?: “I think that for arts patronage to work, there has to be some consensus that the activities of making and…” Apr 12, 14:28
Return to top of page

an ArtsJournal blog

This blog published under a Creative Commons license

Copyright © 2025 · Magazine Pro Theme on Genesis Framework · WordPress · Log in