• Home
  • About
    • For What it’s Worth
    • Michael Rushton
    • Contact
  • AJBlogs
  • ArtsJournal

For What It's Worth

Michael Rushton on pricing the arts

Who bears the burden of auction house fees, buyers or sellers?

January 27, 2015 by Michael Rushton 6 Comments

beast of burdenBlog neighbour Lee Rosenbaum writes today about increases in premiums Sotheby’s auction house, speculating that Christie’s will soon follow suit. She writes:

Here are Sotheby’s new charges (with old ones in parentheses), effective Feb. 1:

Buyers will be charged 25% of first $200,000 (previously $100,000) of the hammer price; 20% of amount above $200,000 to $3 million (previously above $100,000 to $2 million); 12% of excess over $3 million (previously $2 million).

Let’s look at a specific example of how this will work: If your winning bid on an object was $10 million, you would have previously paid $11,365,000 million, including the buyer’s premium. As of next month, it will cost you $11,450,000 million.

Bill Ruprecht, Sotheby’s soon-to-depart president and CEO, issued this statement about the hike:

This will improve Sotheby’s revenue, strengthen the company’s profit margins, fund innovation, help us continue to make interesting and exciting investments in the business, and support our growing online and traditional engagement with clients around the world.

The “clients around the world” who will not feel “supported” by this fee hike are the buyers. They may well declare: “Enough is enough! It’s the sellers [who, in some cases, are charged no commission and even get a cut of the buyer’s premium] who should be footing more of the bill.”

Not so fast.

Auction houses take a cut from sales, meaning that buyers pay more to acquire a work than sellers receive, with the auction house taking the difference. This is similar to what happens when the government taxes a good: buyers pay a higher price than sellers receive, and the state takes the difference. It is as if a ‘wedge’ has been driven between buyers’ and sellers’ effective prices. In auction premiums, as in tax policy analysis, the interesting question is ‘who bears the burden if the size of the wedge increases?’ And the answer does not lie in the side on whom the premium or tax is nominally levied. The allocation of the burden is more complicated that that, because prices adjust in response to changes in premiums (or taxes).

What is the evidence on who bears the burden of auction house premiums? In an economic study of the auction house price-fixing case (and in other papers as well) Orley Ashenfelter and Kathryn Graddy write:

To date, the theory upholds the initial reasoning that increased commissions should have a minimal effect on buyers, with the incidence falling primarily on the sellers.

They reason, and find evidence, that the burden of increases in buyers premiums falls upon sellers.

The reasoning is this: in auctions, the winning bid pays a price equal to the reservation price (the highest total price she is possibly willing to pay) of the second-highest bidder, plus a small increment. That reservation price does not change with changes in buyers premiums. If, for example, the reservation price of the second-highest bidder is $11,365,000 (consisting of a ‘price’ of $10 million and a auction house premium of $1,365,000), that amount does not change with an increase in the rate of the buyers premium. In other words, it doesn’t become $11,450,000 because of some change in auction house policy. Lee Rosenbaum is assuming the winning bid remains at $10 million with the change in buyers premium, but we have no reason to think it would.

The winning bids will fall with an increase in the buyers premium, and that cost is borne by sellers.

Ashenfelter and Graddy:

This analysis would be complete if the number of buyers and sellers in the auction were fixed, and if sellers did not set reserve prices. However, in practice, sellers set a secret reserve price, so that some items go unsold because the bidding does not reach this (seller’s) reserve price. To the extent that buyers are unconstrained by the reserve price, because the item sells for a price higher than the reserve, the analysis above is unaffected.

As Ginsburgh, Legros, and Sahuguet (2004) show, for the situation where the reserve price is binding, however, it is possible that the buyers will end up paying a higher price because of the existence of the buyer’s premium. However, if the reserve price is not binding, and the presence of a reserve price causes the number of bidders participating in the auction to decrease, then prices can be pushed down. This can occur if a buyer’s cost of participating is greater than his expected surplus.

Buyers who fail to purchase or participate in the auction because of the higher commission rates are worse off. In any case, however, this is a second order effect and any harm done to those who do not purchase is not capable of empirical identification. Overall, Ginsburgh, Legros, and Sahuguet (2004) conclude that ex ante, the welfare of all bidders is the same, regardless of the commission [emphasis mine].

So it is sellers who might declare that ‘enough is enough!’

Share:

  • Click to email a link to a friend (Opens in new window) Email
  • Click to share on Facebook (Opens in new window) Facebook
  • Click to share on X (Opens in new window) X
  • Click to share on LinkedIn (Opens in new window) LinkedIn
  • Click to print (Opens in new window) Print

Related

Filed Under: issues

Comments

  1. Rob says

    December 10, 2016 at 4:27 am

    Yes, as a seller, enough is enough! Especially in the case of a small auction house rewarding themselves with 22% premium accross the board. Recently, an item estimated by an auction house at or below $1,000 sold for over one million, premium included. The same item could have sold in estimate and the auction would have received around $220 in premium. Instead, they walked away with over 200k in premium alone, for exactly the SAME amount of work! How can they justify this type of profit, especially after such a huge mistake. Well, lucky them I suppose. What’s next, buyers premiums for realtors? My little antique store has no buyers premium, neither does ebay. Auction houses wont even mention it when attempting to get consignments, no wonder why. If i have to pay 15% commission and there is a 22% premium, i am out 37% no matter how you cut it. Plus added on fees. Where will it end? A small premium is needed for an auction house to survive, after that it is just one of the seven sins.

    Reply
  2. Laurin F. Dykstra says

    March 3, 2017 at 12:58 pm

    The greater public is becoming fast aware of the excessive charges by the large auction houses. Unfortunately, it causes a green stain on otherwise reputable businesses and leaves sellers and buyers with a sense of disgust. Reputation isn’t inexpensive, and this kind of damage could cause, no, I’m afraid will cause clientele to search for alternative outlets. Excessive greed has bankrupted many, many companies, and stockholders are very aware of this situation in business. It is one thing to be in a monopoly and set prices, but quite another when internet businesses are looking for these exact situations to build their own auction houses!

    Reply
  3. John D'Avella says

    May 16, 2017 at 4:49 pm

    I could see paying a 25% buyers premium if yes a guarantee of authenticity

    Reply
  4. Sally Jones says

    June 8, 2017 at 11:27 am

    With all due respect to the comment made by Laurin F. Dykstra, the stain is brown, not green.

    Reply
  5. Ray Govier says

    April 20, 2018 at 5:29 am

    No wonder so many Bargain Hunt ” experts” are opening their own auction houses ! As an auction novice,I always believed that the seller paid the commissions and not the buyer. Shows how naive I am.

    [WORDPRESS HASHCASH] The poster sent us ‘356577745 which is not a hashcash value.

    Reply
  6. auction masters says

    August 7, 2023 at 9:25 pm

    Very informative blog. Simple, effective, and useful too. Continue to enlighten us with your knowledge. Thanks for sharing.

    Reply

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Michael Rushton

Michael Rushton taught in the Arts Administration programs at Indiana University, and lives in Bloomington. An economist by training, he has published widely on such topics as public funding of the … MORE

About For What It’s Worth

What’s the price? Everything has one; admission, subscriptions, memberships, special exhibitions, box seats, refreshments, souvenirs, and on and on – a full menu. What the price is matters. Generally, nonprofit arts organizations in the US receive about half of their revenue as “earned income,” and … [Read More...]

Archives

Recent Comments

  • Carlo on What to do with the NEA? Make it Conservative?: “The Kennedy Center is offering $25 tickets in only select orchestra seating for the performances of Washington National Opera: Porgy…” May 20, 14:17
  • Carlo on Art in Turbulent Times: “The Kennedy Center today is selling discounted tickets for the Washington Opera for $20.” May 1, 21:31
  • Montague Gammon III on Art in Turbulent Times: “We would like to think that a Trumped Kennedy Center would experience a significant downturn in attendance, but we should…” Apr 22, 05:51
  • Ed Comet on What do to with the NEA? Pull the plug?: “The author has gone to the Grand Canyon with a magnifying glass, and found the rocks uninteresting.. The NEA does…” Apr 12, 16:42
  • Brtian Newhouse on What do to with the NEA? Pull the plug?: “I think that for arts patronage to work, there has to be some consensus that the activities of making and…” Apr 12, 14:28
Return to top of page

an ArtsJournal blog

This blog published under a Creative Commons license

Copyright © 2025 · Magazine Pro Theme on Genesis Framework · WordPress · Log in